We
think today that if only we can set up the right social / economic policies
(whether welfare state, or libertarian, or fascist, or whatever) we can assure
ourselves of eternal prosperity—that we will be able to live like the 1950s, or
1990s, forever (ideally with continual technological progress at the same
time).
In
fact the realistic view is that wealth, ‘development level’, social cohesion,
productivity, balance of trade, and so on are all continually changing, both
within a country and in the world outside it. No permanent ‘state’ can be
established—only temporary ‘fixes’. Chesterton said: “All conservatism is based
upon the idea that if you leave things alone you leave them as they are. But
you do not. If you leave a thing alone you leave it to a torrent of change. If
you leave a white post alone it will soon be a black post. If you particularly
want it to be white you must be always paintng it again; that is, you must be
always having a revolution. Briefly, if you want the old white post you must
have a new white post.” (Orthodoxy)
The
medievals called the goddess Fortune, who constantly turns her Wheel and causes
one nation to be preeminent for a time, then to sink into decline and give
another nation its turn. And unlike us the medievals thought Fortune was
arbitrary—wealth, prosperity, power, did not correspond to merit or desert, but
with the chances of the world. I
returned, and saw under the sun, that the race is not to the swift, nor the
battle to the strong, neither yet bread to the wise, nor yet riches to men of
understanding, nor yet favour to men of skill; but time and chance happeneth to
them all. (Ecclesiastes 9:11)
One
thing we do understand today is that wealth, prosperity, and power are not pure
chance, but that human choices have an impact and therefore good choices can
improve one’s chances—but nevertheless it is an important corrective to this
view to realize that time and chance
happeneth to them all. A few historical illustrations:
If
one were to look at the world in the year 1300 and were asked to predict which
nation would be preeminent in wealth, reach, and influence for the next three
hundred years, a good guess would have been northern Italy. Northern Italy was
the wealthiest place in Europe, the most cultured and best-educated with the
best universities, the most rational legal system, the greatest trade
connections, flourishing industry, lively social mobility and free
associations, and—above all—the most advanced techniques for business and
commercial organization and the most advanced technology and science in the
world. Yet Italy’s preeminence did not last even one century, let alone three.
A series of wars, the plague, currency crises, and a number of external forces
combined to throw Italy into a downward spiral which led in a few centuries to
Italy being a notably underdeveloped
nation in comparison with others of its time. And by 1600 the culture of
northern Italy had changed to one hostile to work and business, quite in
contrast to 300 years earlier.
Similarly
if one looked in the sixteenth century Spain and Portugal would appear to be
the natural world leaders. Come back in a hundred years, and it’s the Low
Countries—the Netherlands and Belgium.
In
the nineteenth century everything indicated that Great Britain would be the
preeminent world power of the twentieth century. Her wealth, technology, and
science—greatest in all the world—her navy, her vast empire; how could anything
dislodge this? Yet Great Britain was not the greatest power of the twentieth
century, it was the United States of America. And although there were trends that
could be glimpsed which foreshadowed this, Great Britain’s eclipse by the
United States was brought on above all by the First World War: an external
event with its own chance causes.
No
state of society, no matter how seemingly well-fixed, can persist in a static
way. There will be change from within and also change outside which will alter
its conditions. Therefore, since we cannot be responsible for achieving the
impossible, it cannot be our responsibility to achieve ‘a just society’, ‘a
prosperous society’, or whatever ideal you like—not in the sense of building a
certain structure that achieves this. Our responsibility as social beings must
rather be to do the right thing here and
now—what does justice require now?
what must we do to be prosperous now?—and
the measure of ‘a just society’ would not be permanent structures but rather
dispositions and habits.
This
does not mean without taking thought for the long term, but without imagining
that we can assume what conditions the long term will impose upon us. In this
way social responsibility becomes a macrocosm of individual responsibility—no
reasonable individual attempts to, or imagines that he can, establish a fixed
and permanent ideal situation for his own life; at the very least he knows that
he must age at the rate of sixty seconds per minute and one day indeed must
die. Therefore individual responsibility does not entail making assurance for
the future, but doing the right thing in
the present. Likewise for social responsibility.
No comments:
Post a Comment